1. Número 1 · Enero 2015

  2. Número 2 · Enero 2015

  3. Número 3 · Enero 2015

  4. Número 4 · Febrero 2015

  5. Número 5 · Febrero 2015

  6. Número 6 · Febrero 2015

  7. Número 7 · Febrero 2015

  8. Número 8 · Marzo 2015

  9. Número 9 · Marzo 2015

  10. Número 10 · Marzo 2015

  11. Número 11 · Marzo 2015

  12. Número 12 · Abril 2015

  13. Número 13 · Abril 2015

  14. Número 14 · Abril 2015

  15. Número 15 · Abril 2015

  16. Número 16 · Mayo 2015

  17. Número 17 · Mayo 2015

  18. Número 18 · Mayo 2015

  19. Número 19 · Mayo 2015

  20. Número 20 · Junio 2015

  21. Número 21 · Junio 2015

  22. Número 22 · Junio 2015

  23. Número 23 · Junio 2015

  24. Número 24 · Julio 2015

  25. Número 25 · Julio 2015

  26. Número 26 · Julio 2015

  27. Número 27 · Julio 2015

  28. Número 28 · Septiembre 2015

  29. Número 29 · Septiembre 2015

  30. Número 30 · Septiembre 2015

  31. Número 31 · Septiembre 2015

  32. Número 32 · Septiembre 2015

  33. Número 33 · Octubre 2015

  34. Número 34 · Octubre 2015

  35. Número 35 · Octubre 2015

  36. Número 36 · Octubre 2015

  37. Número 37 · Noviembre 2015

  38. Número 38 · Noviembre 2015

  39. Número 39 · Noviembre 2015

  40. Número 40 · Noviembre 2015

  41. Número 41 · Diciembre 2015

  42. Número 42 · Diciembre 2015

  43. Número 43 · Diciembre 2015

  44. Número 44 · Diciembre 2015

  45. Número 45 · Diciembre 2015

  46. Número 46 · Enero 2016

  47. Número 47 · Enero 2016

  48. Número 48 · Enero 2016

  49. Número 49 · Enero 2016

  50. Número 50 · Febrero 2016

  51. Número 51 · Febrero 2016

  52. Número 52 · Febrero 2016

  53. Número 53 · Febrero 2016

  54. Número 54 · Marzo 2016

  55. Número 55 · Marzo 2016

  56. Número 56 · Marzo 2016

  57. Número 57 · Marzo 2016

  58. Número 58 · Marzo 2016

  59. Número 59 · Abril 2016

  60. Número 60 · Abril 2016

  61. Número 61 · Abril 2016

  62. Número 62 · Abril 2016

  63. Número 63 · Mayo 2016

  64. Número 64 · Mayo 2016

  65. Número 65 · Mayo 2016

  66. Número 66 · Mayo 2016

  67. Número 67 · Junio 2016

  68. Número 68 · Junio 2016

  69. Número 69 · Junio 2016

  70. Número 70 · Junio 2016

  71. Número 71 · Junio 2016

  72. Número 72 · Julio 2016

  73. Número 73 · Julio 2016

  74. Número 74 · Julio 2016

  75. Número 75 · Julio 2016

  76. Número 76 · Agosto 2016

  77. Número 77 · Agosto 2016

  78. Número 78 · Agosto 2016

  79. Número 79 · Agosto 2016

  80. Número 80 · Agosto 2016

  81. Número 81 · Septiembre 2016

  82. Número 82 · Septiembre 2016

  83. Número 83 · Septiembre 2016

  84. Número 84 · Septiembre 2016

  85. Número 85 · Octubre 2016

  86. Número 86 · Octubre 2016

  87. Número 87 · Octubre 2016

  88. Número 88 · Octubre 2016

  89. Número 89 · Noviembre 2016

  90. Número 90 · Noviembre 2016

  91. Número 91 · Noviembre 2016

  92. Número 92 · Noviembre 2016

  93. Número 93 · Noviembre 2016

  94. Número 94 · Diciembre 2016

  95. Número 95 · Diciembre 2016

  96. Número 96 · Diciembre 2016

  97. Número 97 · Diciembre 2016

  98. Número 98 · Enero 2017

  99. Número 99 · Enero 2017

  100. Número 100 · Enero 2017

  101. Número 101 · Enero 2017

  102. Número 102 · Febrero 2017

  103. Número 103 · Febrero 2017

  104. Número 104 · Febrero 2017

  105. Número 105 · Febrero 2017

  106. Número 106 · Marzo 2017

  107. Número 107 · Marzo 2017

  108. Número 108 · Marzo 2017

  109. Número 109 · Marzo 2017

  110. Número 110 · Marzo 2017

  111. Número 111 · Abril 2017

  112. Número 112 · Abril 2017

  113. Número 113 · Abril 2017

  114. Número 114 · Abril 2017

  115. Número 115 · Mayo 2017

  116. Número 116 · Mayo 2017

  117. Número 117 · Mayo 2017

  118. Número 118 · Mayo 2017

  119. Número 119 · Mayo 2017

  120. Número 120 · Junio 2017

  121. Número 121 · Junio 2017

  122. Número 122 · Junio 2017

  123. Número 123 · Junio 2017

  124. Número 124 · Julio 2017

  125. Número 125 · Julio 2017

  126. Número 126 · Julio 2017

  127. Número 127 · Julio 2017

  128. Número 128 · Agosto 2017

  129. Número 129 · Agosto 2017

  130. Número 130 · Agosto 2017

  131. Número 131 · Agosto 2017

  132. Número 132 · Agosto 2017

  133. Número 133 · Septiembre 2017

  134. Número 134 · Septiembre 2017

  135. Número 135 · Septiembre 2017

  136. Número 136 · Septiembre 2017

  137. Número 137 · Octubre 2017

  138. Número 138 · Octubre 2017

  139. Número 139 · Octubre 2017

  140. Número 140 · Octubre 2017

  141. Número 141 · Noviembre 2017

  142. Número 142 · Noviembre 2017

  143. Número 143 · Noviembre 2017

  144. Número 144 · Noviembre 2017

  145. Número 145 · Noviembre 2017

  146. Número 146 · Diciembre 2017

  147. Número 147 · Diciembre 2017

  148. Número 148 · Diciembre 2017

  149. Número 149 · Diciembre 2017

  150. Número 150 · Enero 2018

  151. Número 151 · Enero 2018

  152. Número 152 · Enero 2018

  153. Número 153 · Enero 2018

  154. Número 154 · Enero 2018

  155. Número 155 · Febrero 2018

  156. Número 156 · Febrero 2018

  157. Número 157 · Febrero 2018

  158. Número 158 · Febrero 2018

  159. Número 159 · Marzo 2018

  160. Número 160 · Marzo 2018

  161. Número 161 · Marzo 2018

  162. Número 162 · Marzo 2018

  163. Número 163 · Abril 2018

  164. Número 164 · Abril 2018

  165. Número 165 · Abril 2018

  166. Número 166 · Abril 2018

  167. Número 167 · Mayo 2018

  168. Número 168 · Mayo 2018

  169. Número 169 · Mayo 2018

  170. Número 170 · Mayo 2018

  171. Número 171 · Mayo 2018

  172. Número 172 · Junio 2018

  173. Número 173 · Junio 2018

  174. Número 174 · Junio 2018

  175. Número 175 · Junio 2018

  176. Número 176 · Julio 2018

  177. Número 177 · Julio 2018

  178. Número 178 · Julio 2018

  179. Número 179 · Julio 2018

  180. Número 180 · Agosto 2018

  181. Número 181 · Agosto 2018

  182. Número 182 · Agosto 2018

  183. Número 183 · Agosto 2018

  184. Número 184 · Agosto 2018

  185. Número 185 · Septiembre 2018

  186. Número 186 · Septiembre 2018

  187. Número 187 · Septiembre 2018

  188. Número 188 · Septiembre 2018

  189. Número 189 · Octubre 2018

  190. Número 190 · Octubre 2018

  191. Número 191 · Octubre 2018

  192. Número 192 · Octubre 2018

  193. Número 193 · Octubre 2018

  194. Número 194 · Noviembre 2018

  195. Número 195 · Noviembre 2018

  196. Número 196 · Noviembre 2018

  197. Número 197 · Noviembre 2018

  198. Número 198 · Diciembre 2018

  199. Número 199 · Diciembre 2018

  200. Número 200 · Diciembre 2018

  201. Número 201 · Diciembre 2018

  202. Número 202 · Enero 2019

  203. Número 203 · Enero 2019

  204. Número 204 · Enero 2019

  205. Número 205 · Enero 2019

  206. Número 206 · Enero 2019

  207. Número 207 · Febrero 2019

  208. Número 208 · Febrero 2019

  209. Número 209 · Febrero 2019

  210. Número 210 · Febrero 2019

  211. Número 211 · Marzo 2019

  212. Número 212 · Marzo 2019

  213. Número 213 · Marzo 2019

  214. Número 214 · Marzo 2019

  215. Número 215 · Abril 2019

  216. Número 216 · Abril 2019

  217. Número 217 · Abril 2019

  218. Número 218 · Abril 2019

  219. Número 219 · Mayo 2019

  220. Número 220 · Mayo 2019

  221. Número 221 · Mayo 2019

  222. Número 222 · Mayo 2019

  223. Número 223 · Mayo 2019

  224. Número 224 · Junio 2019

  225. Número 225 · Junio 2019

  226. Número 226 · Junio 2019

  227. Número 227 · Junio 2019

  228. Número 228 · Julio 2019

  229. Número 229 · Julio 2019

  230. Número 230 · Julio 2019

  231. Número 231 · Julio 2019

  232. Número 232 · Julio 2019

  233. Número 233 · Agosto 2019

  234. Número 234 · Agosto 2019

  235. Número 235 · Agosto 2019

  236. Número 236 · Agosto 2019

  237. Número 237 · Septiembre 2019

  238. Número 238 · Septiembre 2019

  239. Número 239 · Septiembre 2019

  240. Número 240 · Septiembre 2019

  241. Número 241 · Octubre 2019

  242. Número 242 · Octubre 2019

  243. Número 243 · Octubre 2019

  244. Número 244 · Octubre 2019

  245. Número 245 · Octubre 2019

  246. Número 246 · Noviembre 2019

  247. Número 247 · Noviembre 2019

  248. Número 248 · Noviembre 2019

  249. Número 249 · Noviembre 2019

  250. Número 250 · Diciembre 2019

  251. Número 251 · Diciembre 2019

  252. Número 252 · Diciembre 2019

  253. Número 253 · Diciembre 2019

  254. Número 254 · Enero 2020

  255. Número 255 · Enero 2020

  256. Número 256 · Enero 2020

  257. Número 257 · Febrero 2020

  258. Número 258 · Marzo 2020

  259. Número 259 · Abril 2020

  260. Número 260 · Mayo 2020

  261. Número 261 · Junio 2020

  262. Número 262 · Julio 2020

  263. Número 263 · Agosto 2020

  264. Número 264 · Septiembre 2020

  265. Número 265 · Octubre 2020

  266. Número 266 · Noviembre 2020

  267. Número 267 · Diciembre 2020

  268. Número 268 · Enero 2021

  269. Número 269 · Febrero 2021

  270. Número 270 · Marzo 2021

  271. Número 271 · Abril 2021

  272. Número 272 · Mayo 2021

  273. Número 273 · Junio 2021

  274. Número 274 · Julio 2021

  275. Número 275 · Agosto 2021

  276. Número 276 · Septiembre 2021

  277. Número 277 · Octubre 2021

  278. Número 278 · Noviembre 2021

  279. Número 279 · Diciembre 2021

  280. Número 280 · Enero 2022

  281. Número 281 · Febrero 2022

  282. Número 282 · Marzo 2022

  283. Número 283 · Abril 2022

  284. Número 284 · Mayo 2022

  285. Número 285 · Junio 2022

  286. Número 286 · Julio 2022

  287. Número 287 · Agosto 2022

  288. Número 288 · Septiembre 2022

  289. Número 289 · Octubre 2022

  290. Número 290 · Noviembre 2022

  291. Número 291 · Diciembre 2022

  292. Número 292 · Enero 2023

  293. Número 293 · Febrero 2023

  294. Número 294 · Marzo 2023

  295. Número 295 · Abril 2023

  296. Número 296 · Mayo 2023

  297. Número 297 · Junio 2023

  298. Número 298 · Julio 2023

  299. Número 299 · Agosto 2023

  300. Número 300 · Septiembre 2023

  301. Número 301 · Octubre 2023

  302. Número 302 · Noviembre 2023

  303. Número 303 · Diciembre 2023

  304. Número 304 · Enero 2024

  305. Número 305 · Febrero 2024

  306. Número 306 · Marzo 2024

  307. Número 307 · Abril 2024

  308. Número 308 · Mayo 2024

  309. Número 309 · Junio 2024

  310. Número 310 · Julio 2024

  311. Número 311 · Agosto 2024

  312. Número 312 · Septiembre 2024

  313. Número 313 · Octubre 2024

  314. Número 314 · Noviembre 2024

Ayúdanos a perseguir a quienes persiguen a las minorías. Total Donantes 3.347 Conseguido 91% Faltan 15.800€

PAVLINA TCHERNEVA / ECONOMIST

“UBI would eventually replace many other welfare programs”

Madrid , 1/03/2017

<p>Paulina Tcherneva.</p>

Paulina Tcherneva.

En CTXT podemos mantener nuestra radical independencia gracias a que las suscripciones suponen el 70% de los ingresos. No aceptamos “noticias” patrocinadas y apenas tenemos publicidad. Si puedes apoyarnos desde 3 euros mensuales, suscribete aquí

CTXT necesita 300 suscripciones mensuales para ser sostenible y cada vez más independiente. Puedes ayudarnos aquí

-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

The foundation in Madrid of Red Modern Monetary Theory (MMT), which aims to achieve a 0% rate of unemployment, presented us with the opportunity of a discussion with one of the main representatives of this economic approach. We are talking about Pavlina Tcherneva: this American economist of Bulgaria origin, is an Associate Professor at the Bard College in New York, of the Levy Economics Institute also at Bard College, as well as of the Binzagr Institute of Sustainable Prosperity. Tcherneva has been able to apply her research and findings to the social reality of numerous countries, obtaining surprising results. Unemployment, the job guarantee and, above all, monetary sovereignty are the main topics of a most inspiring conversation.

Did you know that for Spaniards unemployment is the main problem? What is happening in the United States? Are you really moving to full employment?

In general, many jobs have been created… precarious jobs. We lost many jobs after the crisis. Our labor market recovered according to the official figures, but we did not get back the full-time jobs that we lost. We are especially creating a lot of part-time jobs and these are not exactly voluntary. Moreover, many people gave up and have left the active population which has experienced a major downturn. As people abandon the search for work they do not appear in the unemployment statistics. This is not exactly a solution to the problem, is it? We have other additional indicators produced by our statistical services but they are not given much attention.

And what do these other indicators say?

The official unemployment rate is right now 4.7%, about seven and a half million people; however, if you added to that rate all the people who are not looking for work any longer, the part-time workers that really want a full-time job, then the unemployment rate would be at least double. We could find unemployment rates of 17 million, about 11%, which is very uncommon in the USA, especially in a recovery period.

What is happening to all those people?

To understand this you have to stop paying attention to the official figures. There is a large segment of the population that is now out of the active population. Many economists are going to tell you that this is “structural unemployment”, that they are people who do not have the qualification to get a job, whose jobs have been taken away by technology, that the cost of recovering them for the job market is very high —this is the worst excuse of them all, because the costs have come down everywhere with the crisis—. The job market has become ever more precarious. Social benefits have disappeared, salaries have dropped, we barely have any long-term work contracts, and we barely have trade unions… It is at this point of social failure when certain economists, who have not been able or did not want to solve the problem of unemployment, decide to attach a new label: that this is a natural rate of unemployment. They claim that there is nothing to be done, that this is the market structural unemployment, that it is produce by automation, that the robots are coming….

And it is not scientifically correct. Is it ideology then?

Absolutely. If your ideological commitment is to take no action to achieve secure employment and leave that task to the market, then you should not be surprised to encounter high unemployment figures because the private sector, the market, is always going to do all that is possible to bring down the cost of labor or, if they can, replace it with technology. Because it is only pursuing a profit the private sector frequently finds itself trapped in a vicious circle in which many people are fired, so you need a corrective force. However, if your ideology is anti-State, you cannot even start to think about the policies that you can deploy to correct this situation.

You are proposing a “bottom-up” approach to the problem of unemployment which would consist in the direct creation of jobs. Could this apply to Spain where there are so many unemployed?

The problem is not the quantity of the unemployed. The “bottom-up” approach consists in offering a direct solution to the problem: if your problem is the lack of jobs you have to give people a job. It is so simple! If people need work, you give them a job, not education nor tax rebates for companies hoping that they might then decide to hire…

On paper it looks good, but, in reality?

You have the New Deal of the 1930’s. Another less well-known example: for many decades Sweden had a model in which the State was the employer of last resort. The government, the trade unions and the firms would agree to ensure full employment as the main goal: if companies needed to fire people they negotiated the amount with the trade unions and then those laid off were hired by the public sector. There are, indeed, many direct job creation programs but now they are small. We do not think in the large numbers any longer as they did during the American New Deal.

If the political will exists, then I am totally convinced that the Governments can set up these programs and, moreover, very quickly, in four to six months

What are the chances of implementing this? If the political will exists, then I am totally convinced that the Governments can set up these programs —because I have experienced it besides studying it— and, moreover, very quickly, in four to six months. These are not administratively complex procedures. For example the New Deal was activated in six months and we had 30% unemployment. The Plan Jefes de Hogar in Argentina was introduced when unemployment was 25% and it took off in only four months.

You were an advisor of the Argentinian government just at the time when they implemented a direct employment policy: the Jefes de Hogar Program.

Do you know what they did? They asked the unemployed what jobs they wanted or wished to perform: that really empowered them! The local communities, the parties and trade unions, which are very developed, were the organizers of the program on the ground. The government gave money to the communities and people submitted proposals that had to go through an approval process and, often, these had a direct relationship with what the community needed: a shop to sew school uniforms, clothes for the gym, community gardens, kitchens… People know what they want and, if you allow them to decide what the community wants, the result is tremendously empowering.

Here is a new element: that crude intervention from the State that is always feared does not occur. People are asked…

Of course! For example, in rural areas, the farmers know best. And they let us know that they had irrigation problems and then they developed the project. Even people who lived in the poorest communities in the suburbs of Buenos Aires, who had been neglected for decades, as if they didn’t exist, the poorest people we could find… developed some of the projects on their own: libraries, healthcare centers,… One of the cities I went to was called Ciudad Oculta —Hidden City—, and had been called that way for decades… and one year before the Jefes de Hogar ended they changed the name…

Instead of an invasion from the State, this is about empowering the community. Not everything was perfect: in some areas the program did not work so well… But there was something else and that is that it represented a huge stimulus for the rest of the Argentinian economy: in the first place, more people than expected applied for work, and that is what we call hidden unemployment; the government expected half a million people would participate and two million, 13% of the active population, showed up. In two years the numbers began to drop because people started to leave for the private sector. It was a program in which the government, instead of microcredits that have been so extolled, provided, for example, women with sewing machines and paid them until they could set up their own shops. These women worked a lot of hours even though the government only paid them four, they worked at least eight. They could also end up saving something, investing and creating small enterprises. Things were not the same for people who came out of the middle classes and wanted to return to the private sector… But they also came because they wanted to see their neighbors and feel that they were part of the community. Some people, when they knew about the program Jefes de Hogar, even lent their rooms, garages, … as spaces for the projects, offering their own resources.

In other words it was more than just numbers. We are talking about people… But, how did unemployment evolve?

It came down very quickly from 25% to 7% in about two years. The multiplier effect, 2.5 times, was very high: for each dollar invested in the program two and a half dollars were generated in the Argentinian economy. GDP grew for many reasons besides this program Jefes, at a rate between 8% and 12%... and during this last crisis they haven’t fared that badly…

How was the program funded?

The Government paid in pesos because it had ended the peg with the dollar. When you have a currency board, like they had with the dollar, your capacity to spend is very limited: you cannot increase pesos to spend unless you have obtained the same amount of dollars. If Argentina imports, then it loses pesos and cannot increase public spending which leads to automatic austerity. When they abandoned the currency board and adopted their own currency with their own Central Bank, the peso depreciated but it later stabilized, it was not madness.

Once they achieved monetary sovereignty, the program was funded from the general Budget and final costs did note even reach 1% of GDP. It is not an expensive program at all! The salaries were low, people were only paid for four hours. They should have spent 2% at least.

Then it is not an unbearable cost, as one could have thought.

Unbearable? Look, in Spain the cost of the unemployment insurance is 2.5% of GDP. I reiterate that wages were low. The effects on extreme poverty were very strong because it declined a lot, but not on poverty. This was a negative feature of the program.

 The cost of a job guarantee in Spain would only reach 3% of GDP, or, at best, 4%

Speaking about the job guarantee, there is strong controversy between this concept that you have illustrated and Universal Basic Income (UBI). Is some form of compromise possible? 

I have written extensively about the subject and I have been talking to academics who defend the universal basic income for more than 16 years. We all have the same goals and we are worried about the same problems, but the UBI, in my opinion, solves neither the problem of poverty nor of unemployment. Nor do I think that it empowers people. There are many reasons. In the first place, it has been estimated that the financial cost for Spain would be 20%. However, the cost of a job guarantee in Spain would only reach 3% of GDP, or, at best, 4%. Why? Because it would not apply to everybody, only to those who need it the most.

And only for a period, until the economy recovers… 

Exactly. In the second place, it is true that there are people who should not be forced to work; this is indicative that we could combine both methods. But the unemployed person that wants to work and gets a UBI, even though he surely will not die of hunger, certainly will not get a job. Because the jobs are not there, the market is broken! This is where the problem is, the market does not create jobs because it prefers to automate or do other things.

But there are more reasons. The UBI would end up replacing many other welfare programs, which would be a major problem. How can we defend the minimum wage? They would say: hey, you’ve got your UBI and your basic income, why don’t you go to the market?

From what you are saying the UBI could eventually behave according to the Neoliberal idea: “take your check and spend as you like”.

That is the reason why in the USA the UBI has a strong backing in the Right. Milton Friedman himself supported it. The Left has to know who their ally is: what the Right wants is to eliminate all those social benefits that were won in the past thanks to the struggle of the workers. Besides, if you get a UBI, are you not going to be discriminated in the market?

But the fact is that within the Left there are experts who have been studying the issue of the UBI for years..

But they are rejecting the need for people to participate in the productive process. They want to decommoditize work. But you cannot empower people that way! If you ask the poor what they want, what they are looking for is recognition. Besides, this allows us to drive them to do the things that they themselves need. This is the solution: in the literature on UBI there is a concept called “participation income” where you provide somebody with an income but you require that in return, under the principles of reciprocity and social obligation, that person contributes by participating in socially useful activities; for me, this is the best way to combine the job guarantee and UBI. So, I can support an income for children, for disabled…. But I also allow disabled who wish to work to do so. This is the way to unite the Left in this matter, but as long as a certain Left is determined to disconnect income from work I am afraid that it is a Trojan horse.

However, many say that we are facing the end of work; that the robots are already here…

No. The Left cannot buy this argument. This argument comes from Silicon Valley, from the technocrats who want to automate jobs and kick people out, keeping the profits. That is why they want the UBI.

So that UBI acts as a kind of bailout for private companies…

Exactly! A bailout for companies that want to automate jobs, and that is how they phrase it! The UBI places a veil to structural injustice. What we really need to do is fix the market and make sure that people get work opportunities. The idea that people are going to get a UBI and then will get together and things will come out of there… that’s just not going to happen.

Forgive me for being naive: your bottom-up approach is simple, possible and efficient. Why is not put in effect? In other words, who loses with full employment? 

Well, the thing is that the threat of unemployment represents a huge power exerted against wages. Michal Kalecki wrote about this back in 1944: firms would lose with full employment. In reality, in a mixed capitalist economy, we would all win: more demand, more consumption, more sales, better qualified workers, we would stop paying for diseases caused by unemployment… The job guarantee is a safety net that enhances the human capital of the work force. If the threat of unemployment disappears what happens is that the class struggle between labor and business is drastically altered…

Altered in favor of the workers… But let us turn to the Eurozone. You know that it is right now in a turmoil. Can your bottom-up approach be applied here?

I think that despite everything a direct employment program can be launched in Spain under the current circumstances. And you can even design it so that it costs even less than what you are currently paying for unemployment. In any event, how do you fund a UBI within the Eurozone? It is a lot harder! Look, with a job guarantee there would be many people who would cease to receive unemployment benefits when they enter the program. I you get people out of poverty, those incomes provide to the poor also come down!

Also consider all those unemployed youth: this is a social catastrophe! And it has a high cost that you are already paying for: crime, police costs, security…We are already paying for that! It is a lot cheaper to give people something sensible like a job than to continue supporting them financially, which is the morally correct thing to do but does not empower them at all. You could start with small jobs designed for young people, expand them gradually, associate them to the acquisition of skills and qualifications so that companies later can value that qualification and consider hiring them.

But those who are in power in the Eurozone will not allow it. Look at what happened to Greece…

It was Greece. But now it is going to be Spain, then Italy… they cannot go on doing that. The Eurozone has a very faulty design…. And austerity is going to destroy the Eurozone. It is going to happen. You have to be ready: the first thing you need to do is explain to people that there is nothing natural about austerity and, particularly, that the Eurozone has no precedents in the History of mankind. Normally countries have their own currency; only when you are a colony do you adopt the currency of the metropolis, the colonial power, and you will only get independence if you recover your own currency.

So maybe we are a colony…

Well, it would be a very strange model because you have a voluntary consensus here. A voluntary agreement that consists in separating the government from its money. The USA fought a war for this reason! We wanted our own money and the British did not allow us! You cannot have independence until you have your own sovereign currency under a free-float system. This is why the Eurozone represents an absolutely unique arrangement, because until now there had never been a union in which the government was separated from the Central Bank in such a radical way: it is like a divorce. In the USA there is a separation, OK, but the Central Bank will never bounce a check from the Government. The Fed will never say “No” to a program proposed by the Government and voted in Congress. In Spain you do not have a bank to pay what the government decides. 

There is an added problem. In the Mediterranean countries we are ashamed of our political class and we have always seen our salvation in the European idea.

The same thing happens in Bulgaria where I was born…The idea that Europe solves our problems… The European project begun as a pacifist and progressive project, yes, but the design of the monetary system is killing that ideal: nationalisms are appearing, anti-immigration sentiment… You cannot pursue those ideals of integration and peace when you impose such an unnecessary and severe austerity. If there had federalization, with a fiscal government in Brussels, you could have your own Jefes de Hogar program. You have to decide if that reform is possible. If things go on like this the euro will suffer many more crises and cause a lot more damage, much more than any other alternative. 

In the long-term, would exiting the Eurozone be better? There are a lot of people who say that within the euro crises like the one that we have lived since 2008 can be resisted a lot better…

Think in the alternative? Is austerity going to improve your life? Will it get worse if you have monetary sovereignty even under a corrupt government? Continuing with austerity is going to cause salaries to fall further, more privatizations… When the Government spends in the USA it does it with new money that is advanced by the central bank. The central bank backs all the checks that the Government gives to contractors, who later pay taxes to the government. This money paid in taxes cancels the money created initially. Opposite of what is commonly thought, to collect taxes first you need to spend.

Now, if I am a company and the government pays one hundred dollars and charges twenty in taxes, those 80 will remain in my bank account; they are dollars created by the bank that I have. But in the Eurozone you do not have your own Government that can deficit spend and this is very important. If the Spanish Government needs money if has to borrow it from a bank; this bank never advances money to the Government. That is why, in Spain, to spend you either collect taxes or you borrow money. There is a dissociation between the issuer of the currency and the user.

Let’s do an exercise: if the government spends 100 and taxes 20, the private sector keeps 80. Those are their savings and also the government deficit. People are so afraid of the deficit…. But the Government deficit is the private sector surplus; is their savings! Therefore there has to be some agent who, so to say, dissaves.

So the pitfall is to think that deficits are bad per se. It’s a fetishism.

Exactly! Deficit phobia is, possibly, the greatest obstacle to do what we want to do. People believe that you have to comply with austerity… and what happens in reality is that if one agent saves another has to borrow. The idea of austerity is completely unnatural. For, what happens if the government has a surplus? What happens if the government spends 100, gives 100 to the private sector and taxes it with 150? What happens to the private sector?

That it runs into debt.

In runs into debt. So what do we want, that the government borrows so that the government balances the Budget? It’s total madness!

That is what you call functional finance: nothing happens without consequences. The public deficit is the private savings. It’s a system. Once you see it that way, everything else becomes easier. But we the Spaniards, the Greeks are accused of working too little, working on the side, collecting subsidies. There is a certain cultural racism that makes everything worse and undermines our credibility even if we present good alternatives like the one you explain….

In the United States the same things are said about African Americans. Think about this: you cannot know who is lazy and who isn’t unless you reach a full employment situation. Only if the Economy provides a sufficient number of jobs for those looking for one, then, only then, can you know who works the most and who the least. But if your economy hast two people and generates only one hob, you can do whatever you like with the second person: train them, coach them, give them a PhD, computer skills… but she will never have a job. It’s like the musical chairs: if there are only nine chairs then tenth individual, no matter how much computer knowledge she has, will not get one. So the market is not creating enough jobs and we can always say that that person is lazy, that she is happy with subsidies… but in reality it’s the other way around. Each time people think about those people you are making an assumption that never happens, that the Economy produces enough jobs.

If we leave the euro, investors, lenders will lose confidence, inflation will come and all the ghosts haunting us…

Those are myths. If the Peseta [the former currency of Spain] returns you do not depend on lenders to lend you Pesetas because the Pesetas will come from your central bank. You do not have to borrow it because you are the monopolist of the peseta.

But can there not be an inflationary spiral? You know, print, print, print….

Yes, it can happen. How can it happen? It the Government spends, it does so because it needs something. If the Economy produces that something there will be no inflation. If you keep spending but you do not get what you need then it will generate it. In Japan they had the largest public debt in History, but the creditors did not punish them because they had a Central Bank. However, even with the largest debt in World History, they’ve had twenty years of deflation. And they do not create jobs because they are not doing it directly.

With MMT, is there a return to the classic, regulator, and Interventionist State? 

Modern Monetary Theory has no particular political orientation, it only explains how the monetary system works and that, if you have monetary sovereignty, you don’t tax to spend, it’s the other way around, first you spend, and then you tax. That is the first point. Once people understand this, if you see that you have unemployment, you can bring taxes down, because there is nothing bad with the deficit. What matters is where we spend. Besides, the job guarantee proposal empowers people, it frees them, in fact. Social participation increases, the State just finances. This has progressive implications because we end the myth of the budgetary constraint and we see that many impossible things become possible. And then we can see what people want. And then you can get to the conclusion that the financial sector is too large and you go ahead and regulate it… but that’s a different story…

To finish I would like to ask you about Donald Trump’s economic plans. Sometimes he appears to be like Roosevelt, sometimes like a total libertarian. What would have happened if Bernie Sanders had become president?

Sanders is phenomenal. He would have won the elections if the Democratic Party had chosen him, they made a total blunder. There would have been real change. About Trump, I do not think there is a contradiction: in his first days he is behaving like what he is, a Neoliberal. He is terminating publicly funded programs, freezing spending… he’s privatizing the public sector. Although he may use a populist language, he is providing incentives to the private sector in many ways so that they build infrastructure. His policies are reactionary. There could be a good effect in the long-term if he increases deficit spending. But he could be our worst Trojan horse…

------------------------------------------------

Traducción de Stuart Medina Miltimore/Red MMT Spain

CTXT necesita 300 suscripciones mensuales para ser sostenible y cada vez más independiente. 

Suscríbete a CTXT

Orgullosas
de llegar tarde
a las últimas noticias

Gracias a tu suscripción podemos ejercer un periodismo público y en libertad.
¿Quieres suscribirte a CTXT por solo 6 euros al mes? Pulsa aquí

Artículos relacionados >

Deja un comentario


Los comentarios solo están habilitados para las personas suscritas a CTXT. Puedes suscribirte aquí